Main content
AP®︎/College Microeconomics
Course: AP®︎/College Microeconomics > Unit 2
Lesson 8: The effects of government interventions in markets- Rent control and deadweight loss
- Minimum wage and price floors
- Price and quantity controls
- How price controls reallocate surplus
- The effect of government interventions on surplus
- Taxation and dead weight loss
- Example breaking down tax incidence
- Taxes and perfectly inelastic demand
- Taxes and perfectly elastic demand
- Tax Incidence and Deadweight Loss
© 2023 Khan AcademyTerms of usePrivacy PolicyCookie Notice
Rent control and deadweight loss
Price controls have the potential to reduce total surplus. In this video we step through some details on how one kind of regulation, a price ceiling, can reduce economic efficiency. A real world example of a price ceiling is rent control, which some cities have experimented with as a way to control rising housing costs. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- Why would the suppliers not want to supply more than the point in the middle of the graph?(8 votes)
- Because either they won't be able to sell any of that product, or they won't make a profit in doing so. Here's why:
The demand curve is downward pointing because every subsequent copy of a product bought by a consumer is less valuable than the last. To put it simply, lets say you buy one orange, then two, then three until you have 100 oranges. By this point you're starting to get pretty damn sick of oranges, you won't have time to eat them all before they go rotten etc. If you have no oranges and buy one, you are now gain +5 happiness. the next orange adds +4 happiness, the next adds +3 and so on. Total happiness is still increasing from 5 to 9 to 12, but the individual happiness of each individual orange is decreasing. Economists have simply called this marginal benefit and the law of diminishing marginal returns.
The exact same thing happens for suppliers, and it's called marginal cost. In this case every subsequent orange costs more than the last one to grow and harvest. Why is this the case? Because now we need to hire more people and more farming space to produce more oranges, it now costs companies more for each individual orange that is produced.
Combine these two forces together and this is what happens: Consumers want lots of oranges, some consumers are orange lovers and will be prepared to pay lots for oranges (left side of demand curve), some are casual consumers who will only buy them if the price is right (right side of demand curve). The same thing happens for suppliers. Some suppliers have more fertile soil, or can hire staff cheaper. They are prepared to sell their oranges for a small price (left side of supply curve), while others have more costly land and staff and have to charge more per orange (right side of demand curve.)
This means that the people on the right side of the demand curve have to pay the EQ price just to buy oranges. They think that this price is too high (price is greater than happiness recieved from oranges) and will not buy them at the EQ price. If the price is lowered they would however.
Unfortunately suppliers on the right side can't afford to sell oranges at the EQ price. Their cost base is too high and they could only sell oranges at a higher price. They would sell more oranges at a higher price.
You can see the problem now. To supply more oranges we have to raise the price, but then less oranges will be bought by consumers. We could lower the price, but then orange suppliers would start leaving the market. The EQ position is the most efficient compromise between consumers and producers.
Hope that it helps! :)(72 votes)
- What would the consequence of increasing a price ceiling be? For example, applying this to a real world scenario, UK tuition fee caps tripled from 3k to 9k a few years ago - what would this do to the market?(7 votes)
- Increasing the ceiling (bringing it closer to equilibrium) would decrease the effects of the price ceiling.(22 votes)
- Sal talks about "Deadweight loss," but is society really losing money? Where does that loss of money go?(8 votes)
- Society, more precisely, members of the society will lose well-being, the term "losing money" does not mean much in the context. Just consider this: if I raise the price of gasoline by 100%, people will not "lose money", people just won't be able to afford to buy as much gasoline as before.
The same applies to all these deadweight loss examples: people do not lose money in the natural sense. There are simply people who could not benefit from voluntary exchange because of the rent control and this means a well-being loss for them.(17 votes)
- How about " the black market" if price ceiling apply to it.(3 votes)
- The other way of thinking about a black market when you have a price ceiling on the regular market is that a price ceiling creates a shortage. IE if bread is capped at 25 cents you will get long lines and run out of bread (IE USSR in the 1980s). Above the equilibrium point you will have a new supply curve (of producers willing to skirt the law) and demand from people willing to skirt the law). The slope of these lines will likely be different than the original supply and demand curve but where these intersect you will have a "black market clearing price".(4 votes)
- I don't understand why we care about surplus areas, as they seem to me completely theoretical (consumer or producer COULD gain something if the price was different). Why lessening of these area is talked about as a loss. The second question is: It is hard to believe in the direction of the supply curve, it seems to me natural, that producing more units requires less cost for a unit, not more. I would greatly appreciate if you answered my questions(10 votes)
- You can see the increasing demand curve as the increasing opportunity cost(1 vote)
- I'd like to know what happens to the deadweight loss. Would it go to the government since they set the price ceiling?(3 votes)
- That's the thinking behind the whole idea of the deadweight loss: it does not go to anybody. It is lost welfare.(9 votes)
- I don't understand. Shouldn't the new price ceiling price line (the dotted white one) be drawn all the way to the demand curve? Why did Sal stop drawing it when it touches the supply curve. If he draws it and it touches the demand curve, then the consumer surplus would actually be greater than before.(4 votes)
- The reason Sal stopped the dotted white line at the Supply line, is because the suppliers won't produce more than that point, since Marginal Benefit equals Marginal Cost, and producing more will not be profitable for them.
You can draw the line to the Demand line for yourself, and see that the producer surplus would drastically drop (you have to subtract the area UNDER the supplier line. The consumer surplus would indeed increase, IF suppliers would produce more than the market equilibrium, but that's the case for every scenario(6 votes)
- Can anything else cause a deadweight loss or is it basically just artificial causes such as the price ceiling from this video?(3 votes)
- There are a few things that can create deadweight losses:
1. Price ceilings
2. Price floors
3. Taxes
4. Subsidies
EDIT: it was pointed out to me I was wrong. There are multiple other, natural, causes of a dead weight loss.
5. Monopolies, oligopolies, and monopolistic competitive firms (that covers most firms in the US economy)
6. Externalities (like pollution and second hand smoke)
7. Non-rival (like street-lights) and non-exclusive goods (like fish in the ocean)
8. Asymmetric information (like insider trading or improper identification of the side-effects of taking a drug, etc.)(7 votes)
- What happened to the other 1m sqft of rental space when the cap hit?(2 votes)
- Many times, the leftover space that does not get rented out ends up either not being taken care of (basically, the landowner is lowering that marginal cost curve to match the lower price that was forced on them) or if that doesn't lower their costs well enough they end up trying to get that space off their hands. Often, that leftover space turns into an abandoned building.(7 votes)
- Is the price ceiling always place under the market equilibrium price?(1 vote)
- In theory it's possible that there's a price ceiling above the market equilibrium price. But in practice you probably will never see one. The goal of a price ceiling is to protect customers from high prices. So a government might decide that to keep rice affordable they enforce a price ceiling of $10 per kilo. But if the current market price for rice is $5 per kilo there's no problem of unaffordable rice, so the government would probably never set up the price ceiling in the first place; it would be useless.(5 votes)
Video transcript
Voiceover: Let's think about
the market for real estate in a given city. Here on the vertical axis I have plotted rent in terms of dollars per square foot per month. Here on the horizontal axis, is essentially the quantity of square foot square foot per month
available in millions. This is 1 million, 2 million, 3 million, 4 million, 5 million. Here in blue we have the demand curve. You see as the price is high, one way to view it is that the demand for square footage is low and as the price is low the demand for
square footage is higher. But what I really want to
focus on in this video, is viewing the demand curve as the marginal benefit curve. Marginal benefit curve. When that first incremental square foot that is added to the market, that has a huge marginal benefit where people are desperate
to get an apartment. To get someplace where they
could rent and they could live. So it has a huge marginal benefit. Then the marginal benefit for every incremental square foot starts to go down. Likewise, we can look at the supply curve. We're going to look at this as the marginal cost curve. The marginal cost curve. The marginal cost of that very first incremental square foot for the suppliers for the landlords in the city is $1 per square foot. One way to think about it, that very first square foot, we don't know what its
price would have been, but let's say its price
was at $3 if it was. I'm just making that up. In that reality, if that very first square
foot's price was at $3, there is definitely an
incentive for someone to make that first square foot because their marginal cost is only a dollar and they could
rent it out at $3 per month. There is definitely an incentive
for someone to rent it. The marginal benefit is
$4 and they just have to pay $3 for it. It could be rented out for anywhere or it would exist, or this kind of transaction would happen as long as its price
was between $1 and $4. You could imagine, based
on how this is drawn, where the actual equilibrium price is. The suppliers will keep
adding more and more square foot as long as they
can actually rent it out, all the way until the
point that the marginal benefit is equal to the marginal cost. Right over here marginal benefit is equal to marginal cost. It wouldn't make sense for suppliers to produce an incremental
square foot right over here. If they produce an
incremental square foot, their marginal cost has gone beyond $3, while the marginal benefit is below $3, no one is going to rent that thing out. We reach an equilibrium point at 2 million square feet per month on the market. Let me make that line a
little bit straighter. 2 million square foot
per month on the market and at a price of $3 per
square foot per month. You can look at the total surplus here. In this equilibrium scenario, we can calculate the consumer surplus. So all of these folks, for this first incremental foot, someone was willing to
pay $4 per square foot. They only have to pay $3. The next one a little less than $4. Benefit they only have to pay $3. All the way to this point right over here. So the area of this
triangle right over here, this right over here is
the consumer surplus. So that right over here
is consumer surplus. Consumer surplus. We can calculate it. This is a triangle. I'm assuming actually both the
supply and demand curves are lines. So let's see this has a height of 1 and it has a base of 2 so
its area is going to be 1 times 2 times one-half. That is going to be equal
to 1 million dollars. We are multiplying $1 times 2 million times one-half. That's going to be 1 million dollars of consumer surplus per month. Let's think about the producer surplus. The producer surplus is
going to be this area. It's going to be this
area right over here. That first incremental foot it only cost those producers $1 but they are able to rent it out for $3. Then they will keep producing, keep producing all the way until they do 2 million square foot. For all of their square feet, they are able to rent it out for more than it was their cost to produce it. So the area of this triangle
is the producer surplus. This is the producer surplus. Producer surplus. We can calculate that as well. The height right over here is $2. $2 times this width is 2
million square feet per month. 2 times 2 times one-half is 2. This is equal to 2 million dollars. If we were to talk about
what the total surplus is, it is 3 million dollars. Now, this equilibrium rent, $3 per square foot per month
is actually quite a lot for 1,000 square foot apartment. My last apartment was a two bedroom, two bath apartment. It was about 1,000 square foot. So that means you're
going to be paying $3,000 per month for that. That's pretty high rent. That's the type of rent you might pay in a city like San Francisco. Let's say people start
complaining about it. So the government says,
"Okay that rent is not fair. "It's too high. "We want to introduce some
type of price control. "We want to introduce rent control." I'm oversimplifying how this works, but just so that we can deal
with this model right over here, Let's say that the city
just sets a ceiling on the price per square foot per month. Let's just say they set a price ceiling, a price ceiling of $2 per
square foot per month. $2 per square foot. Let me write it this way. $2 per square foot per month. So they set a price
ceiling right over here. Given that, what is going to happen? What is going to happen? What I really want to think about is what is going to be the new consumer surplus or the new producer surplus? I encourage you to pause the video and try to think about that on your own. Well let's think about
what's going to happen. From the producers point of view, it doesn't make sense for them to produce more than 1 million units. 1 million square feet per month. I have to rent out more than a million square feet per month because that extra square foot above that, its marginal cost is going to be more than what they're going to get. The producers are just
going to stop there. The producer surplus
is going to be the area of this triangle right over here. Let's see, this is $1 times 1 million times one-half. This is now a producer surplus. Producer surplus. A new producer surplus
under the rent control of $500,000, half a million, of $500,000. So we see that the rent control immediately hit the producers pretty hard. The producer surplus has
gone down dramatically. Now what about the consumer surplus? We're talking about a million units, or a million square foot
per month I should say. So now the new consumer
surplus is the area, is this entire area. So you see that at least for this first incremental million square feet, the consumers have started
to win out a little bit. To figure this out,
what the total area is, we just need to figure
out what we could break this up into two sections. We could break this up into two sections. This is the point, 1 million square feet at $3.50
dollars per square foot per month. This is right over here,
the point, the 3.5. We could use that to
figure out this new area. Actually let me do it
in a different color, in this green area right over here. What is it going to be? Well the area of this
thing right over here is one-half high. One-half times 1 times one-half. This right over here is 250K. We add that to this area right over here, which is one and a half times 1. $1.5 dollars per square foot per month times 1 million. Did I do that right? Yep. So that's going to be plus ... plus this, which is 1.5 million. You add these two together. The total consumer surplus ... So the total consumer
surplus is now 1.75 million. So the consumer surplus definitely did go up in total because it gained all of this from the producer, but let's think about what has now happened in our society or in our city. The producers definitely
don't want to put out as many square foot per rent anymore. It does look like we have lost some total surplus for our little city here. We have lost out on this entire area. We can calculate it by looking at what the total surplus was
before the rent control and what the total surplus
was after the rent control. The total surplus before, so before the total
surplus was the 2 million producer surplus plus the
1 million consumer surplus, so it was 3 million. After, it is the 1.75
million consumer surplus plus the $500,000 producer surplus, which is 2.25 million. What we've lost is the difference here, which is $750,000. So this area right over here. This is per month. This right over here represents
the lost total surplus. This lost total surplus
of $750,000 per month is referred to as the dead weight loss. You can debate about rent control. Is it good? Is it bad? Is it good for this kind of dynamic? Who gets what share of the surplus? This of course is an oversimplification of a market and even the way rent control would be instituted. This is a model for beginning to think about what happens to the total surplus when these types of price
controls are instituted.