Main content
Macroeconomics
Course: Macroeconomics > Unit 8
Lesson 2: National income and inequality- Capital by Thomas Piketty
- Difference between wealth and income
- What is capital?
- Piketty's two drivers of divergence
- Is rising inequality necessarily bad?
- Convergence on macro scale
- Education as a force of convergence
- Gilded Age versus Silicon Valley
- Inverse relationship between capital price and returns
- Connecting income to capital growth and potential inequality
- r greater than g but less inequality
- Return on capital and economic growth
- Critically looking at data on ROC and economic growth over millenia
- Simple model to understand r and g relationship
© 2023 Khan AcademyTerms of usePrivacy PolicyCookie Notice
Connecting income to capital growth and potential inequality
Inequality is a fact of life in market economies. Learn about income inequality in a market economy, how it's measured, and its connection to capital and growth. See how the top 10% of earners' share of national income has changed over time. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- At, Sal says that the added green section is the growth of the economy. However the total green circle represents the income of the economy as a whole. So it is the growth of income right? and not the growth of the economy? 6:50(6 votes)
- Income and GDP are the same thing, thus income growth and GDP growth are also the same thing. There are three approaches how we can look at GDP: the income, the expenditure and the production apporach. This simply means that these three concepts can be matched: what income is for one person, it is expenditure for another, what is being produced by one person, it is going to be bought by someone else, so it is expenditure as well, etc...
Try watching some of the earlier videos connected to GDP to get a clearer understanding of the subject.(6 votes)
- At, the top decile having a smaller share of the economy? Would it be pertinent to discuss whether it was affected by the war or by the Glass-Steagall Act (which appears to correspond roughly to the same period)? Do you have an opinion as to whether it affected income inequality at that time? 1:46(2 votes)
- This is a graph of one way of measuring income inequality - it's not the only way, but it's probably as good as any.
The primary drivers of this graph are the health of the economy and the top marginal income tax rate in the US. During FDR's Depression, income tax rates were increased to over * 90% * for the top bracket. With rates that high, top income earners did everything possible to hide income in unrealized capital gains, which are not taxed as income. Therefore the apparent income level drops as more and more money is in unrealized capital gains. Then in the 1980s the top tax rates came down - as people slowly adjust to the new normal, they hide less and less income in unrealized capital gains, and so the apparent top income levels grow.
Note, it's also neat how you can see the 2000 stock bubble and the 2007 stock bubble on the graph, though it's delayed slightly. (I assume the delay is because they're using income tax returns for the year, and during the bubble many people had realized capital gains that counted as income.)(6 votes)
- Assume that the national economic growth is 5%, and the growth of income to capital is 10%, I want to know how this could be a force driving inequality between the top decile and the rest of the country, given the fact that capital is unevenly distributed among the top 10% earners and the other 90% ?(2 votes)
- The assumption is that inflation-adjusted labor income would grow at 5%, but inflation-adjusted capital investment income would grow at 10%. So those with capital investment would (over time) pull away more and more from the sellers of labor.(4 votes)
- I understand that capital concept of Piketty consists of production capital + family property capital. That's contrast with GDP (additional value), and the rise rate r's big is the cause of unequality, isn't it? The distribution with the taxation is necessary to settle "donation economy". I approve wealth taxation, but BASIC income is also indispensable.(2 votes)
- Hey Sal, thanks for these amazing videos. I was wondering if there are any practice materials to help strengthen my understanding of the lessons learnt from each video?(2 votes)
- In the beginning he says that ending inequality could halt or slow economic growth. That doesn't seem self-evident, and I'm not sure why it would be the case. Is that discussed in another video?(2 votes)
- How is he measuring national income? Is that GDP, or just that first component of GDP?(1 vote)
- National income is not GDP. It is actually something called GNP, which Sal explains towards the end of the video at https://www.khanacademy.org/economics-finance-domain/macroeconomics/gdp-topic/circular-econ-gdp-tutorial/v/parsing-gross-domestic-product.(1 vote)
- Does Piketty deal with the fact that the people who from 2008 through 2010 and probably beyond achieved more than 50% of the nationals income by stealing it with the collapse of the economy and having their golden umbrella's to protect them? We saw a huge jump of capital with CEO's becoming richer while labor dramatically declined. How do economists account for the fact that money is being unethically stolen or passed around creating a bigger inequality for the rest of the nation? I am referring to people like Enron, Lehman Brothers, etc. Maybe these people had a little jail time but in the end, are living higher on the hog and do the economic equations account for this when dealing with inequality?(1 vote)
- @What does top decile means ? Should not it just mean 10% of the population? Whether top denotes top wealthiest person or persons having highest share of national income? 1:21(0 votes)
- Top decile means the top 10% of some quantity. In this case the share in national income by the top 10% decile. So in 1940 the top 10% of the population has a little over 40% of the national income.(3 votes)
- So what are the forces that grow the economy to determine inequality? Does the increase in capital play a role in the strengthening of the economy? or is it the other way around?(1 vote)
Video transcript
- [Sal] We've already talked quite a bit about the idea that if, look, if you have a market,
capitalist economy, that some, that this will lead,
hopefully, to economic growth, economic growth, but by definition, a market economy will have
some folks who win more and some folks who don't do as well, and it's going to, you're
also going to have inequality. Inequality; so inequality is
essentially a fact of life of a market economy,
and it's not necessarily something that you just wanna turn off, because that might also
hurt economic growth, and that actually might
make everyone better off because the economic growth
on a per capita basis could also be benefiting people who aren't in the top percentile
or decile or quartile. Not always, but it could be. But with that thought
in the back of our mind, let's actually think a little bit more about inequality and how it's measured, and how it can be tied
to things like capital and growth of income to
capital and returns on capital. So this right over here, this
is from Thomas Piketty's book, and what's neat is he's
made all of the charts of his book available
online, right over there, and this shows income
inequality in the United States between 1910 and 2010,
and what you see here, he measures it by the share of top decile in national income. So top decile's the top 10%,
so this point right over here tells us that in 1910,
the top 10% of earners made a little over 40%
of the national income. As we go into the late
20s, that approaches 50% of the top, the top 10% of earners were making close to half
of the national income. And then as we go through
the Great Depression, and especially after World War II, this drops down into the low 30%s, and then from the 1980s to the present, this has crept back up
to the high 40% range. So the top decile, the top 10% of earners, are making close to half
of the national income. Now let's just visualize how
this happens, just numerically. So let's imagine this is
your economy in year one. So this is your economy in year one. Actually, let me copy and paste that. I think that'll be useful. So copy, all right. And let's say that this is the fraction, I'll do it in orange, that
is going to the top decile. So let's say it's roughly
a third in year one. So this is the fraction that's
going to the top decile. This is 1/3 right over here. So the way that you have rising, so on this chart, this
would be kind of a 33.3, so it would be someplace around here, so we could pretend like we're some date in the 60s or 70s right over here, and now the way that you
have this chart moving up, where you have the top decile having a larger and larger
share of national income, is if this orange section grows faster than this green section. So for example, this grew by 10% while this grew by 5%, by 5%, over time this orange section is going to take a larger and larger chunk of the green section. Now as we saw in previous videos, even if this does happen,
and this is by definition rising inequality, there
could be a scenario where the other 90% are
still having a bigger pie, and on a per capita
basis still might be able to be better off. But the focus of this video is not that. The focus of the video is tying this idea to the idea of increasing
returns on capital driving this phenomenon,
driving inequality, income inequality. So as we've seen before, income and wealth are not the same thing, but
wealth could be a proxy. The more wealth that
you have, you will have more income from that wealth. You will have return on that capital. So another way to divide the economy is instead of thinking
of the top 10% of earners and the other 90% of
earners, you could think of how much of this income goes
to the owners of capital, and how much of it goes to the
people who provide the labor? So it's more of a labor-capital split versus the bottom 90%-top 10% split. So here we could think of
this section right over here, and I'll just make it a different, so let's say this is right over here, this is how much is going
to owners of capital, to capital, to owners of capital, the people who own the
buildings, the real estate, the resources, and how
much of national income is going to labor. So this right over here,
this right over here is going to labor. Now the same, a similar idea is, look, if this blue section grows, consistently grows faster
than the green pie, then the percentage of
income that goes to capital is going to grow more and more and more, and because in capitalist market economies capital is also not evenly distributed, mainly because income is
not evenly distributed, because capital is not evenly distributed, that this would essentially lead. As more and more income goes to capital and that capital is
disproportionately owned by the upper decile of income or wealth, then you're going to,
it's essentially going to drive this phenomenon right over there. Now I wanna be very clear. This growth right over
here, you'll hear the term return on capital in
conjunction with Piketty's book where they compare the return
on capital to growth rates. This growth right over here
is not the return on capital. In order to know the return on capital, you have to know how much,
you need to know the income that the capital generated,
but you also have to know the value of that capital,
and here in this diagram, all I know is the income
that the capital generated, but I don't know the
value of that capital, so I can't calculate
the return on capital. This growth that I'm
showing right over here, maybe after a few years
this blue section grows to over here, while the green section, while the pie has grown
something like this, this growth right over here, you could view this as the
growth of income to capital, which isn't something
you hear a lot about. But this growth right over here, this growth, maybe this is
plus 5% for the total economy, this is the G that's often referred to. This is the total growth of the economy.