Main content
Macroeconomics
Course: Macroeconomics > Unit 8
Lesson 2: National income and inequality- Capital by Thomas Piketty
- Difference between wealth and income
- What is capital?
- Piketty's two drivers of divergence
- Is rising inequality necessarily bad?
- Convergence on macro scale
- Education as a force of convergence
- Gilded Age versus Silicon Valley
- Inverse relationship between capital price and returns
- Connecting income to capital growth and potential inequality
- r greater than g but less inequality
- Return on capital and economic growth
- Critically looking at data on ROC and economic growth over millenia
- Simple model to understand r and g relationship
© 2023 Khan AcademyTerms of usePrivacy PolicyCookie Notice
Piketty's two drivers of divergence
The video discusses two theories for increasing income inequality: 1) Top managers getting a larger share of income due to market recognition or self-regulation, and 2) Capital-driven inequality, where people with more capital see their wealth grow faster than the economy. It also mentions how higher incomes lead to higher savings rates. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- at, Sal said that the doctor invested his inheritance at a rate of return that is growing faster than the economy. Is there even such a type of investment in the real world? If so, can't everybody just invest in that and all have dynastic wealth? 5:18(21 votes)
- As I mention above in another answer: Ultimately, for the entire society as a whole, return on all capital (including the capital that is known as "labor") must equal the output of society. However, when we talk of return on investment capital we must keep in mind that some people want to borrow, and not save. The borrowers (such as credit card users), drive up the return on investments, to a level above the return on the capital of society as a whole. This is because the borrowers are consuming more than their share of the output, since they're consuming more than they earned.
So yes, if you don't consume much relative to your income, you can increase your relative share of equity over time. You can however only achieve dynastic wealth if the increase in share is sufficient to be split across all heirs, or you engage in the now archaic practice of primogeniture. Th excellent book (fascinating to be so old and yet so relevant to today at times) The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith goes in to, among other things, the idea that primogeniture was partially responsible for the 1000+ year medieval economic depression. If you've never read it, you should.(27 votes)
- Right at the end of the video, Sal asks us to think critically about why the equation r > g will not hold up forever. Let me try:
I think it is because if more and more people accumulate greater wealth, then less people will work because they can live off the return on capital invested (r).
However, at some tipping point, when too many people quit working, the economic growth (g) will become stunted. As r relies on the growth of the economy, r will start to deteriorate together with g. At some point further in time, r < g because of (example), government defaults on bonds, causing the return on capital invested, r, to become zero.
In short, r < g happens during a recession or deleveraging.
Kindly point out my mistakes (if there are) and state any other reasons why r > g is not sustainable.(8 votes)- what do you think about technology investment? may be the economy does not need people to work. people just be a mamager of their investment and the robot or machine will do all stuff. then the economy growth is going to keep growing(4 votes)
- Why does it matter if R>G? If you're getting large returns on capital, you could still not be required to work.(9 votes)
- Out of interest. Is return on capital in any area consistently larger than the growth rate of he economy?(6 votes)
- The problem is that determining the growth of "the economy" as a whole requires arbitrary and non-objective value judgements.
If in year 1 we did nothing but farm, and in year 2 we did nothing but eat last year's food and build houses, did the economy grow or shrink? How do you compare a year of food vs a year of houses? What if nothing was ever bought or sold - everyone just farmed their own food and built their own house? This is an extreme example, but it speaks to the fundamental problem that you can't determine objectively the growth of the economy as a whole.
Ultimately, for the entire society as a whole, return on all capital (including the capital that is known as "labor") must equal the output of society. However, when we talk of return on investment capital we must keep in mind that some people want to borrow, and not save. The borrowers (such as credit card users), drive up the return on investments, to a level above the return on the capital of society as a whole. This is because the borrowers are consuming more than their share of the output, since they're consuming more than they earned.(8 votes)
- Sal talks about return on capital being greater than the growth of the economy. Could you explain why the growth of the economy is important. If a person can make a ROC of 10% and the growth of the economy was a crazy 15% (compared to the 1-4% we typically see), why is this 15% important? Could you please use an example to support your explanation, for easier understanding. Thank you.(6 votes)
- The implication is that if "the economy" grew by 15% that both the productivity and the wealth of everyone grew by that amount. It could in theory happen that growth exceeded investment return, but you would need to import factors of production from other countries - ie, most likely by immigration of a huge number of new workers.
It doesn't really tell you anything for certain about the percent of wealth the person now holds. (Maybe the immigrants are rich, and his percent went down significantly.)(6 votes)
- If R<G, does that mean the person who invest their money is losing their money?(3 votes)
- No. It just means that the whole economy is getting larger faster than the person is making money. So, in other words, the total size of the pie is getting bigger faster than the investor can increase his own slice.(11 votes)
- What do the wealthy people do with their savings?(3 votes)
- I assume they can do anything they want with their money ranging from continuing to save it, spending it themselves in any variety of ways, giving it to charity/relatives/friends, or using it in ways that are broadly designed to provide a future economic return which could very well include investing, loaning and minimizing their taxes. I would guess often times they might do some kind of combination of all those things.(2 votes)
- what do u mean by the growth is lower than the return on capital? how that would be?
give me a example please.(3 votes) - Could we view people who earn more , as those saving more and therefore investing more in capital and therefore being those who are actually making the economy grow ? Then the return of capital will be good an the growth shall be also good . For those who doer their money through labor more than through capital , they can be viewed as being more in demand as they will be required more and more as the country grows in economy. So essentially if you do not have the rich denying the actual people for labor cost, your economy grows rapidly. Correct me if I have gone horribly wrong somewhere.(2 votes)
- I think what you're describing is roughly the argument for "trickle down" economics which I believe is essentially: if you provide an environment of lower overall taxes then those with capital will invest their money in ways that will grow the overall economy and provide a rising tide for everyone. I think the ultimate test for that theory is determining whether or not people with greater economic resources actually do invest those resources in ways that grow the overall economy or whether they use that extra income to enhance their own wealth and not use it in a way that grows the economy and provides jobs.(1 vote)
- Is there a point at which the return on capital will become so excessive that output can't keep up, which would then result in a decrease in the return on capital? Is this an indicator of an economic downturn or recession when this tipping point is reached?(2 votes)
Video transcript
Voiceover: Before going into depth and to some of the other charts of the book. Let's think about what's
Thomas Piketty outlines is the two theories why we have this increasing income in inequality
in the United States. One theory is that it's driven by labor, it's driven by layer, labor and in particular you
have this phenomenon. So this is, you have this phenomenon where top managers,
where we're talking about executives maybe of large corporations are getting a larger and
larger share of income. Larger share of income. And he argues that this
could be due to one of two reasons or maybe some combination of them. One might be the market
just recognizing the value or the importance of having top managers. And so over the last few
decades the market has realized "Hey, it's worth it to pay these folks "more and more and more money." Because even though
those are large salaries these are a very very large enterprises and if you can measure
that someone can drive a one or two or three percent better return on capital for
multibillion dollar company or drive the growth faster for a multibillion dollar company then maybe it's completely worth it to giving them a larger and larger and larger share of income. So one possibility, one possibility is just the recognition. So let me write this way, this is the market recognition of value. Market recognition of value. But another thing he sites, and he actually implies and
this is what he believes is the more likely one, is that over the last several decades you had situations where the top managers have been able to essentially control what they themselves get compensated and there's not a lot of
checks and balances there. So this is the one that he actually argues is probably happening more. So, you can almost say this is kind of a self regulation of income. Self regulation and most folks, if they are allowed to
self regulate their income would tend to increase it, or maybe it is a combination of both. So this is one dynamic that he argues could be driving this
increase in inequality that top managers are getting a larger and larger share of income. The other one is driven by capital. So the other argument
is one based on capital. So capital, and it's all around the idea if the return on capital
is greater than growth than over generations,
those who have capital, especially those who
generated this proportion of share of their income from capital, are going to if their
proportion of income, their proportional wealth is going to grow become a larger and larger and larger share of the economy. What do we mean there? Well, if most of your income is, comes from just your, from your labor, then your salary is just
going to be based on market forces for how much value you might be able to add to a organization and how many other people have that skill, and your negotiating leverage and all of those types of things. But if most of your incomes
starts to be generated not from labor but from
returns on capital. So what do I mean by that? Well let's say that you are, let's say that you are a doctor, you are a doctor, and let's say you make $200,000 a year. So $200,000 a year, this is, let me do this in color
that you can actually see. $200,000 a year, this is your income, this is your income from labor. Income from labor. But let's say that you
come upon some inheritance and you have a 10 million
dollar inheritance, so you have a 10 million
dollar inheritance, and you invested, and you get a 5 percent return on it. So you're return on capital is five, so you get five percent, so let me write this, R is equal to five percent here. R is equal is to five percent. Well five percent of 10 million dollars is $500,000. $500,000 per year. So this right over here
is income from capital. Income from capital. And so his argument here is, is once you get to a certain point and you start having a lot of capital, and if your return is greater than the growth in the economy, well then this, this
doctor in this example. His wealth is going to go from 10 million to 10.5 million, it's going to grow by five percent again, year in, year out, it's going to grow
faster than the economy. And then he could, I guess bequeath to his
children or to someone else, and then they will be able to compound in the same way, and then over time, you might have some
form of dynastic wealth, where wealth is being
driven really you know, they don't really need to have a job. And just this phenomenon by itself, where you inherit some money, you invest it at a rate of return that is growing faster than the economy, and so this overtime is going to take up a larger and larger chunk of the economy. And I'll do a spreadsheet to kind of show at least this dynamic. Now he also points out, that look there could be other dynamics that bounce this off. In fact maybe this is one
of the dynamics that really, I guess you could say,
valued labor, whether, and we see that in some are areas, whether it's a sports
stars or maybe in finance, where the best hedge fund manager is a portfolio managers who get a disproportion share of income. Maybe some of that is justified, or maybe you know even get this returned, you need some of it to go to a labor, but it goes the other way as well. When people get huge labor income that might allow them or
potentially the people that they bequeath their money to, to kind of go into this
category right over here, where they are getting a
lot or all of their income or disproportionate share of their income from the return on their capital as opposed to their labor. And that's, this whole idea is really that you're just going to have a higher savings rate if
you have a large income. And actually let me
make that clear as well. So for example, for example, if, let's say there's two people, one person, so person A
and person B, person B. Let's say person A makes a 100,000 a year. 100,000 a year. And let's say that person B, let me do those in the right colors. Let's say person A makes a 100,000 a year, and let's say person B makes 1 million. 1 million a year. Let me just write it this way. He makes 1 million a year. So that's their income, and we're not even saying
how it's coming to them, whether it's labor or returns on capital. So that's their annual income. Now person A, you could consider them I guess upper middle class, they might have you know a mortgage, or house payments, send their kids to college, whatever. Their expenses might be 80,000 a year. Expenses are 80,000 a year. And let's say this is after
tax just to make it simple. After, this is after tax income. So their expenses are
going to be 80,000 a year. And so they will be left to save, so their savings, savings are going to be $20,000 per year. Now let's say person B
their after tax income is a million dollars a year. Now they are able to live a more glamorous life I guess and so they have might more expenses. Maybe they spend, and you know maybe their families are the exact same size. Maybe they spend, I don't know, five times as much money. So this person is living a much more consumptive lifestyle
I guess you could say. So they are spending $400,000 to live. And so their savings are
going to be $600,000. $600,000. And so you see this idea that this person right over here
has a 20% savings rate. They are saving 20% of
their after tax income, 20k out of a 100k, while this person right
over here has a 60, 60% savings rate. Now it's completely
possible that this person could really you know live large and spend 800,000 a year. But it's this phenomenon that
the larger that this goes, it's actually hard to
spend that much money. In fact you could imagine if someone with a lower income, 40,000 or 50,000, where they have to
spend all of their money and they actually have zero savings. So as you, as your income, as your after tax income
becomes larger and larger relative to your standard of living, your cost of living. The savings rate generally goes up. And because the savings
rate generally goes up. You start to go more into
this category right over here, where you benefit, where you might benefit from returns of capital, especially if returns of capital are growing larger than the, going larger than,
faster than the economy. And another question to ask is "Do you think this could happen "over very long periods of time?" So once again my point
here is to really just to articulate what's going
on in this what now seems to be a pretty, pretty popular book. But you should look at
this one with an open mind, but also at a critical mind. Does this make sense? What are the balancing factors? Why this might not continue forever? Why R can't be greater than G forever? Or why this might break down? Or why this won't continue
on and on forever?