Main content
Microeconomics
Course: Microeconomics > Unit 7
Lesson 5: Oligopoly and game theoryWhy parties to cartels cheat
In this video, we explore a conflict that duopolists (and other oligopolies) face: there is a tension between cooperating and forming a cartel or cheating on that cartel once it is formed. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- How does OPEC maintain stability if there's an incentive to cheat?(26 votes)
- In the past the price has remained the same because Saudi Arabia has reduces their output of oil to keep the price artificially high. Saudi Arabia has the largest reserves of oil still in the ground, so they have a higher incentive to keep the price high. The incentive is that in the future, when these other countries start to run out of oil, Saudi Arabia will still have untapped oil that can be sold at an artificially high price.
I hope that makes sense.(59 votes)
- Wouldn't the honest firm figure out the cheating firm is cheating if the product started being sold at $8.00 instead of $10.00? Also, why would the honest firms marginal cost go up if the honest firm is not cheating? If they're sharing MC you'd think they'd share MR. I keep getting stuck on if the cheating firm's MC is greater then their MR, they'd have less of a profit even though they sold more.(13 votes)
- 1st Question: Yes, it would eventually realize it´s being conned. It´s explained in the next video in more detail.
2nd Question: The "honest´s" firm marginal cost would not go up, It´s the "market´s" that would do so.
3rd Question: MR does not have to be greater than MC for the firm to be making profits. The difference of these values represents the profit that would result from producing an additional unit. In this example there is a "global" loss of profit by producing more units; however, the cheating firm is forcing (by cheating) the "honest" firm to bear the complete weight of that loss.(16 votes)
- Doesn't this only hold true if the cartel parties are only interested in their economic interests above all else? i.e., if a cartel forms as a means to exact revenge, then the desire for all the members to have revenge on the outside parties would be stronger their their collective economic interests, therefore there would be less incentive to cheat. If a cartel forms as a means of social change, then the members' desire to bring about that social change may be stronger than their individual desires to make more money. My point being, cartels may form for many reasons but economics may not always be the main reason so cheating can be mitigated by stronger incentives than financial gain.(6 votes)
- And all of what you mentioned is studied under the relatively new branch of economics called "behavioral economics". In this model, many assumptions are made to keep it simple (i.e. firms only looking out for personal financial gain).(5 votes)
- Wouldn't the equivalent of both firms cheating essentially be "legal", or at least result in a competitive market? What happens to each firm's MR if both cheat?(4 votes)
- I think this is implicitly answered in the next video. When both parties cheat as much as they can total economic profit goes down to zero which means perfect competition per my understanding.(5 votes)
- Why do the cheating firm and non-cheating firm have the same average total cost of $8? I would expect that if the cheating firm produces 35 units and the non-cheating firm 25, they would be at different points along their (identical) ATC curve and hence have a different average total cost. (though the price they get per unit of good will be the same)(6 votes)
- the cheating firm needs to decrease the price so they get more customers instead they need to decrease quantity and increase price so they get less bro(0 votes)
- This is a wonderful lecture, but I'm confused by one of the pre-conditions: Why would the marginal production cost increase with the number of units created. Wouldn't economies of scale drive per unit cost the opposite direction?(3 votes)
- In reality marginal cost "curves" are not curves at all. They are usually jagged and sometimes discontinuous functions. They may go down over some sections (and usually do), but ultimately they must go up at the end. Eventually at large enough scales you will being to bid up the cost of factors of production such that they increase your cost per unit.(3 votes)
- The video is a very clear explanation, thanks. But here's what I don't get: parties to cartels have strong incentives to cheat, but in reality, cartels or duopolies I've come across seem to never cheat? Also, this explanation assumes the price is based on produced units, but don't cartels often collude a fixed price and it's up to each firm to coordinate production costs and control the output flow so that they maintain high profit margin?(1 vote)
- The short answer to your question about cheating is that cartels, etc. have an incentive to cheat in a non-repeated game but that incentive may be reduced in a repeated game. In other words, in real life most cartel members have to deal with each other in the future, and not just in one period.
It gets somewhat complicated mathematically, but intuitively, in a repeated game, the colluding firms will have to coordinate in the first period as well as future periods. Every firm must have as its strategy set something like: "if a firm cheats in period 1, I will produce the competitive quantity (as opposed to the smaller cartel quantity which would give each firm a larger profit) in every period thereafter." So the cheating firm will get relatively large profits in period 1 (from cheating) but relatively small profits in each period thereafter (because every other firm will start producing the larger competitive quantity).
It is important to note, that the other firms must be willing to utilize the punishment strategy - in other words, the threat of producing the relatively larger competitive quantity must be credible. The credible threat will keep the other firms from cheating provided the stream of future profits is greater for the firm when it doesn't cheat compared to the stream of future profits when cheating.(7 votes)
- Is this what xbox and playstation are doing? They essentially have a duopoly when it comes to consoles, are they therefore on purpose causing stock shortages to manipulate pricing and earnings?
Same thing might be said about Nvidia and Amd when it comes to stock shortages of their new graphics card?(3 votes) - Is there any real world example of such a case happening?(2 votes)
- Sneaky, which reminds me of Amazon, because I believe they try to intimidate small businesses and all others around them to force them to cooperate and sell their products through them.
Not cool. >:(
They literally made a warehouse and never used it and never sold it, a total waste of money and land.
A big bruh!(1 vote)- yeah capitalism is a pretty messed up system(2 votes)
Video transcript
What I want to do
in this video is analyze why it makes sense
for two companies that make up a duopoly to coordinate. To get into an agreement,
which may or may not be legal-- probably would be illegal--
and restrict quantity. But also think about why
there's a strong incentive for either or both
of the parties to cheat their agreement
and produce more quantity than they agreed to produce. So let's say that both of
our players in our duopoly-- and this would actually apply
to an oligopoly generally, but the analysis would be a
little bit more difficult if we had more than two
players-- but let's say each player has an identical--
they're identical companies. And they both have a
marginal cost curve that looks something like that. So they both have an
individual marginal cost curve that looks like that. And they both have an
average total cost curve that looks something like this. And they are identical. So I'll just draw it once. This is the marginal
cost and average total cost for both firms. Now let's think about what it
would look like for the market. Well, one way to
think about it-- pick an arbitrary marginal cost. So for one firm, what
can they produce, or what quantity will they
be at that marginal cost? Well, they'll be
at this quantity for that marginal cost. But if you have two firms
that are just like that, they could have twice
as much quantity to be at that point
in marginal cost. So two firms will be over there. And if you picked
this marginal cost, one firm would
produce that quantity to be right at
that marginal cost, for that next incremental good. But two firms could
produce two, especially if they have the exact
same cost structure. So what you're going
to have is you're essentially adding
this curve to itself in the horizontal direction. So if you look at the marginal
cost curve for both firms together, you're
essentially going to get a curve that is twice
is fat as the marginal cost curve for one firm. So it will look
something like this. And I'll do it in yellow. So it will look
something like that. So that is the marginal
cost for the market, where the market in this example
is both of these firms. And that will also be true
for the average total cost. If at this price--
or actually, I should say, if the average
total cost is up here for one firm-- that
means that they are producing this quantity. But two firms together could
produce twice the quantity of that average total cost. So two firms would
produce twice. And so what you're going to have
is an average total cost curve that is twice as fat as
the average total cost curve for one firm, if
you talk about the market. So the market's average
total cost curve is going to look
something like this. It's going to be twice as fat. It's the exact same logic. It's going to look
something like that. So that is the average total
cost curve for the market. So, so far, the convention
that I've ended up using is orange for an
individual firm, and then this dotted yellow
line for the market as a whole. Now let's think about
what a good equilibrium-- or what the right
price should be if they were able to
coordinate together. If they were to essentially
combine their firms and almost behave like a monopoly. And to think about
that, we're going to have to draw a demand curve. So let me draw the
market demand curve. Let's say the
market demand curve looks something like that. It's really big, so
it's hard for me. And we'll assume
that this is a line. So it's not-- well,
that's pretty good. So this is the
market demand curve. So if both of these firms
operated together, if they-- I drew the market demand curve. I also want to draw the
market marginal revenue curve. Now remember, we're going to
assume that both of these firms are acting together. If they perfectly coordinate,
they can join their capacities and act essentially
like a monopoly. So if they did act
like a monopoly, their marginal
revenue curve would be twice the slope of
this market demand curve. So it would hit the horizontal
axis right over there. And so it would look
something like this. So this right over here is the
market marginal revenue curve. So if they were to
behave like a monopoly, you could view this dotted line
as their marginal cost curve. This would be their
average total cost. And now this is their
marginal revenue. If they were to
behave as a monopoly, what would be the
optimal quantity? Well, it would be right there,
right where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. Before that, they
would keep wanting to produce because
marginal revenue is higher than marginal cost. And then after that, they
don't want to produce, because marginal cost is
higher than marginal revenue, and they're going to
take economic losses on each of those
incremental units. And so this is the quantity
that they would produce. And the price they would
get for that-- they just have to go to the
market demand curve-- they would get this
price right over here. Let's say they would get
that price right over there. And the actual-- their average
total cost per unit-- once again, we have to go
to the market here. It's this dotted
line right over here. That is their average
total cost per unit. So their average
economic profit per unit is going to be their
revenue per unit, minus their average
total cost per unit. So this height is their
economic profit per unit. And if we multiply that times
the total number of units, you would get their
total economic profit if they coordinate perfectly,
essentially behaving like a monopoly. And let's just say for
argument that this height right over here-- let's
say that that is 10. And let's say that
this quantity that they would want to produce
as a monopolist is 50. So what is the total
economic profit here? Well, their total
economic profit is 500. Total economic profit if
they coordinate is 500. And so they see this, and
they say, look, why don't we agree to each produce
exactly half of this, and we would split
the economic profit. And to see that, let's
just say one firm says, OK. They both decide that
they're going to produce 25. They're going to get
this price for it up here, which was
the market price. They're going to get
that price for it, and their costs are right here. Now we're going on
each individual firm. And that makes sense,
because this cost is just twice as far away as this cost. And the dotted line
yellow average total cost for the market is just a
fatter version, twice as fat as the orange line. And so each firm will make
this much economic profit per unit, times 25 units. And so each firm would
make this orange area in terms of economic profit,
or half of the entire 500, or 250 per firm. Now let's think about why
there is an incentive for one or both of the firms to cheat. Let's say one firm
in particular-- so the other firm
holds at 25 units. But the other firm says,
hey, I like this price. I'm already making
economic profit. Let me produce 10 more units. So the other firm says, I'm
not going to produce 25. I'm going to produce 35 units. And if that guy
produces 35 units, and the other firm in the
market-- the other duopolist, I guess we could say it--
continues to produce at 25, then the total market production
is now going to be 60. Now what is the total
economic profit? So we can go up the demand
curve right over there. That's the new price. That right over there
is the new price. The cost per unit is
this right over here, and then the number of units
that they're producing is 60. So the new economic
profit is this area, in this bluish purplish
color that I just drew. And even visually this is true--
looks like the demand curve and the average total cost curve
have gotten closer together. So let's say that this
height right over here is 8. And it's going to be $8 of
economic profit per unit, times 60 units. So if they cheat--
let's talk about the cheating circumstance. This was coordinate, now let's
think about if they cheat. Now we have 60 units
for the whole market times $8 of economic
profit per unit. You're going to have total
economic profit of 480. Your total economic
profit went down. And that makes sense,
because now as a market, you're producing
beyond the point where marginal revenue is
equal to marginal cost. Now marginal cost as a market
is higher than marginal revenue. And so all of this
is essentially, you're creating economic
loss because each of these incremental
units as a market-- The cost is higher
than the revenue, and you have an economic loss. And so that's why your total
economic profit as a market went down from 500 to 480. But how much is this
character going to be making? The one that decided to cheat? Well, he now has 35 units. He's producing 35
units, and he's getting an economic
profit of $8 per unit. So he gets this entire
area right over here. So let's multiply 35 times 8. I'll do it right over here. 35 times 8. 5 times 8 is 40, 3 times
8 is 24, plus 4 is 280. So now the cheating
firm, Cheat, has $280 of economic
profit in this period. And then the honest firm, or the
fair firm-- what they're both doing might be illegal by even
attempting to coordinate-- the non-cheater, I guess
I could call them-- the non-cheater
will have the rest. The non-cheater is going
to have the balance of the economic profit. And the total economic
profit was 480. The cheater's getting 280. The non-cheater is
only going to get 200. So the cheater
definitely benefited by increasing quantity
past that optimal one. He went from 250 to 280. So it made sense for him. It reduced the total
economic profit, and it really hurt the
non-cheat right over there.