Main content
Microeconomics
Course: Microeconomics > Unit 7
Lesson 1: Perfect competition- Introduction to perfect competition
- Perfect competition and why it matters
- Economic profit for firms in perfectly competitive markets
- How perfectly competitive firms make output decisions
- Efficiency in perfectly competitive markets
- Perfect competition foundational concepts
- Long-run economic profit for perfectly competitive firms
- Long-run supply curve in constant cost perfectly competitive markets
- Long run supply when industry costs aren't constant
- Free response question (FRQ) on perfect competition
- Perfect competition in the short run and long run
- Increasing, decreasing, and constant cost industries
- Efficiency and perfect competition
© 2023 Khan AcademyTerms of usePrivacy PolicyCookie Notice
Long-run economic profit for perfectly competitive firms
A firm in a perfectly competitive market might be able to earn economic profit in the short run, but not in the long run. Learn about the process that brings a firm to normal economic profits in this video.
Want to join the conversation?
- If a firm knows that in the long run they will make zero economic profit, why do they even bother producing at all? Why would an entrepreneur devote their entire life to operating a business, if they will (at least in the LR) only break even?(5 votes)
- The key here is the fact they will be making zero economic profit in the long-run. If they're making zero economic profit(normal profit) this means that they're making a positive accounting profit which means that they're actually making money. Remember that economic profit takes into account the opportunity costs as well, not just the actual money being made.(9 votes)
- What is the name of the point in which marginal cost and average total cost curve intersect?(2 votes)
- We would call that marginal/total cost equilibrium, or just Equilibrium. Graphically, we would label it P*Q*, for price equilibrium and quantity equilibrium.(4 votes)
- How come that the implicit costs are counted in the ATC curve? So that the firm knows it makes normal economic profit - isn't it derived only from the fixed and variable costs? Where are the implicit costs?(2 votes)
- ATC in the short run is derived from the total fixed cost and total variable cost that include the implicit cost. In terms of economics, mostly cost will include both implicit and explicit costs.(2 votes)
- What does it mean conceptually to be productively efficient in perfect competition? Any Khan videos on this?(1 vote)
- Productive efficiency is just producing at the most efficient price, and the most productively efficient point is the minimum point of the Short Run Average Cost curve. In order to be as productively efficient as possible, you want to be at the point where MC = SRAC(4 votes)
- Does a competitive firm’s price equal its marginal cost in the short run, in the long run, or both?(2 votes)
- A competitive firm's price will equal its marginal cost in both the long and short run.(1 vote)
- In firm A what is the price where they will make an economic profit(1 vote)
- What is it that “is the best for the long-term health of the company and society”?(1 vote)
- I am not convinced that the graph on the right stands for firm A's cost. My opinion is that only on a graph of the average cost level of the industry can any outside firm decide whether it is profitable to enter. And different firms in the industry are endowed with their own production technology and thus cost function, so they have different decisions whether they exit.(1 vote)
- What is short run equilibrium of a firm?(1 vote)
- What if too many firms exit the industry and causes the price to shift to the point where it is even lower than the ATC, would that be considered a long-run scenario? or something else?(1 vote)
Video transcript
- [Instructor] Let's
dig a little bit deeper into what happens in
perfectly competitive markets in the long run. So what we have on the left-hand side, and we've seen this
multiple times already, is our supply and our demand curves for our perfectly competitive market, and you can see the equilibrium
price right over here, marked with this a dotted line, and as we've talked
about in multiple videos, the firms in that perfectly
competitive market, the perfectly competitive firms, they just have to price takers, so the market price is going to be their marginal revenue curve. It's gonna be this horizontal curve. And it would be rational for
them to produce the quantity. So they're not going to set the price, but they can choose what
quantity to produce, but it would be rational
for them to keep producing while the marginal revenue is
higher than the marginal cost up to including when the marginal revenue is equal to the marginal cost. So for this firm at this
current state of affairs, it would be rational for them to produce this quantity right over there. And as we've talked about in other videos, at that quantity, they're going
to make an economic profit. And the way that we can see that is at this quantity, this
is the average total cost, that is your marginal revenue, and so you are going to
get this much per unit and then you multiply, so the height is how much you get per unit and then you multiply that
times the number of units, so the area of this rectangle is that positive economic
profit that this firm will have. Now, that's in the short run,
but now let's think about what will likely happen in the long run. If folks see other folks making
a positive economic profit, remember, economic profit
doesn't just account for regular cost, it also
includes opportunity cost, so a lot of you will say hey,
I would wanna put my resources into this market so that I can make that positive economic profit as well. But what's gonna happen as you have entrance into this market? Well, that's gonna shift the
supply curve to the right. At any given price, you're
gonna have more supplies, one way to think about it. So that's a supply curve. Let's just call that one. Now, you're gonna have more entrance. More entrance. And what's going to happen? Well, you might get to
something like you might get to a situation like this. Let me see if I can draw it well. You might get to a situation like this where you have more entrance and you got the supply curve two. Now, what's going to be the quantity that firm A produces in that one? Remember, firm A is one of many firms. Well, in this situation, we
have a new equilibrium price. So if this was P sub one, now we have this new
equilibrium price, P sub two, which is going to define a
new marginal revenue curve for all of the players in this
perfectly competitive market and so the new marginal revenue curve is gonna be right over there. Now, in this situation, what
is the rational quantity for firm A to produce? Well, once again, as
long as marginal revenue is higher than marginal cost, it makes sense for them to
produce more and more and more, up until the point that they are equal. So now, firm A would want to produce less because the market price that
it just has to take is less. But notice what happens
as more and more entrants got into the market. The market price, which also defines this horizontal marginal revenue
curve, went lower and lower to the point where firm
A now in this situation is making no economic profit. At this point, where not
only as marginal revenue intersecting marginal cost, but that's exactly the point in which marginal cost is
equaling average total cost. So one way to think about it is in a perfectly competitive firm, they're productively efficient. They are producing the quantity that minimizes their average total cost. We've already talked about that point where marginal cost and
average total cost intersect. That's gonna be the minimum
point for average total cost. And why is that? Well, while marginal cost
is below average total cost, average total cost is gonna
get lower and lower and lower, and then once marginal cost gets higher than average total cost, well, then the average total cost curve will starting going curving up. So we just saw a situation that even where we see economic
profit in the short run, in the long run, entrants are
going to go into that market and it's going to reduce the
economic profit down to zero and at that point, the firm
that has a zero economic profit, they're productively efficient. They are producing at the minimum point of the average total cost curve. And we've already talked before that this equilibrium point
right over here in our market, because our demand and supply curves, the intersection point defines the price, our equilibrium price and quantities, we're also allocatably efficient. We've talked about things like
dead weight lost in the past. That is not happening right over here. Our marginal benefit is
equal to our marginal cost right at that equilibrium
price and quantity. Now, some of you might be saying, well, what about the other situation? What about if for some
reason we were in a, let's call the supply curve here. Let's say people overshot. Too many people joined into this market. So let's say we went
to supply curve three, well what's going to happen? Let me label this. This is right over here, this
is marginal revenue curve one, which is equal to price one. This is marginal revenue curve two, which is equal to price two. And then this would define,
so this right over here would be price three, price three, which would define marginal
revenue curve three. So marginal revenue curve three, which is equal to price three. Well if too many entrants
joined into that market, now firm A has a more difficult scenario. They are, would produce at this quantity, we've talked about many times already, but at that quantity, each
unit their average total cost is higher than that
revenue they're getting. So they're going to be
running at an economic loss in the short run. But what would happen in the long run? Well firm A in the long run
would probably exit the market and other firms who are
running at economic loss would exit the market,
and so that would shift the supply curve back to the left. And so we would eventually
get, once again, to that reality where firms
have no economic profit in there and we have a market
that is allocatably efficient, no dead weight loss,
and firms are producing at the minimum point of their
average total cost curve, which is known as productive efficiency or productively efficient.