Main content
Macroeconomics
Course: Macroeconomics > Unit 3
Lesson 2: Historical circumstances explained by AD/ASReal GDP driving price
Thinking about how high utilization could drive price as another justification for an upward sloping short-run aggregate supply curve. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- If firms want to increase their output and they have to increase wages, this leads to a higher average price level, Then, since their costs have risen, they will rise their prices but workers will demand a higher wage due to inflation. This would again increase demand and so on... when does the loop close? Will inflation just keep on going? What happens to the firms' revenue?(2 votes)
- think of it like this, when a firm increases output they hire more labour, this would keep the average cost of production constant but total variable costs would increase. if demand for the product rises and the supply the firm can produce cant rise any more then
-price will rise to meet demand
- workers will demand higher wages
a firm maximizes its revenue when the marginal production of labour is equal to real wage rate..
this means that a firm wishing to maximize profits should hire additional workers until a point where they hire a worker who's production matches their wage AKA MPC=6 W/P=6. This happens because of diminishing returns to scale.When thinking about returns to scale think of a bakery shop.. hiring one more person doubles your output, four people in the kitchen its running smoothly but your not all very busy, with six people someone is just in the way and you actually get less done than you could with five people employed. this is an example of " economies of scale"(1-4 workers) and then "diminishing returns to scale" 4-6 workers(1 vote)
- While saying sticky prices or wages , do we always assume the short run being those sections of time where the contracts are in progress and not those intersections of expiries of old contracts and drafting of new ones ?(1 vote)
- Yes, when contracts are in progress, when prices are very difficult to change. However, different contracts expire at different times, so it will be a smooth transition.(2 votes)
- What would happen if basically Prices goes up but the supply of goods and services stays the same. What would be the factors which could cause such effect?(1 vote)
- The equation that explains this is: M * V = P * Y
Where M = money in circulation
V = velocity of money (how quickly the money that exists gets spend)
P = prices
Y = amount of goods and services produced
From this you can see two reasons for prices to go up. The first one is that the government decides to print more money. If you read about a country with hyperinflation this is always happening.
The second one is when people spend the money they have faster.(2 votes)
Video transcript
Male: In our earlier justifications
for an upward sloping aggregate supply curve in the short run, we kind of viewed price as
the independent variable. What I want to explore a
little bit in this video is that you could view
it the other way around. You could view that real
GDP is driving price. Just to review, this
is our upward sloping, the thing that we want to happen. Aggregate supply in the short run. In the previous videos we said, hey, when price increases,
this would cause real GDP to maybe expand even beyond its potential, beyond its natural rate. Let's say that this is
where it is in the long run, right over here. Let me draw it. This is where it is in the long run, right over here. This is an aggregate
supply in the long run. This is the current level of prices. This is all review. Right over here, this is
our current level of prices. This is where we're sitting on GDP. In the past we said, hey,
if we increase prices because of a bunch of
factors, that might cause, in aggregate, the economy to produce even above its natural rate,
so you would actually have real GDP expanding, so you have an upward sloping aggregate supply curve. We gave reasons why price
might drive this to happen. We talked about the misperception theory, that individual actors in the economy, individual firms, might misperceive the increases in prices as a microeconomic phenomenon and so they would, because of the law of supply, they'd think they were
making more real profit. It would take them some time
to realize that they aren't. It's just nominal profits
that they're getting. On top of that, we talked about the whole sticky wage, sticky cost theory, that some part of the
economy there will be increased real profits
because in the short term, some players' costs aren't going to go up as much as their revenue are, so they would also want to essentially produce more beyond their
natural productivity and maybe overheat their factories and their people a little bit. But I want to talk in this video, and this is true of a
lot of economic models, you don't have to view
price as driving real GDP. You could really just view
it the other way around. As real GDP, if you get
utilization really, really high, approaching 100%, and depending on how
you define utilization, maybe going even above 100%, that that might actually drive prices, or that maybe they are driving each other. One way to think of it, and really this is just another justification
for an upward sloping aggregate supply curve, but we're just doing it a different way. Now we're saying this is our
natural rate of productivity. If we're asking people to produce more, then they're going to want to charge more. The way to think about
this, and at the end it's really not going to help them because everything's going
to get more expensive. They're going to produce more
but they're not going to, on a per unit basis, not
get much more real profit. But in the short run they might, or they might think they are, so they might want to do it. The one way to think about this is if you view this bar,
the area of this bar, as the capacity of a firm,
the capacity of a market, capacity of an entire economy, then maybe its natural, its potential, maybe it's sitting here
at maybe 85% utilization. If the factory could be
producing widgets or cars or whatever 100 hours a week, its natural state is it's actually only producing 85 hours a week and
that's because it needs to use that other 15
hours to let the factory cool down, or to do
repairs and maintenance or inspections of some sort. But let's say that for whatever reason, maybe a war starts, and the government demands that more things get built, more widgets get built,
more tanks get built, more materials need to be developed, that they're essentially
asking people not to do some of these things that
they would have to do if they want to be
sustainable in the long run, and they ask the
factories to produce more, to start getting to 90%, 95%,
maybe even 100% utilization. You can imagine in this situation all of the firms ... a firm
is all about maximizing profit ... they will
raise prices when they can raise prices even
though in the long run it will just be a nominal increase. It won't necessarily be a real increase, but they'll feel in the
short run that it is kind of a real increase in prices, and so they will do that. Instead of them trying
to build more capacity, they might even view it
as a short run thing, so they'll say, hey,
no, you're going to have to pay us a lot of money for our employees to work overtime. Maybe that's even in some of the contracts that you have to pay more
for them to work overtime, for me to defer some of my maintenance and other things that I
was going to going to do, or kind of defer investment for me to just produce all out right over here. I'm just describing the
same upward sloping curve but with a different narrative. Instead of saying that price
is driving real GDP expansion because of the misperception
theory and sticky prices, I'm saying that an increase in real GDP and an increase in
utilization will drive prices. They're just two ways to
look at the same thing. You can even apply that
to some of the ideas that we talked about in the last video. In the last video, you might
not have even had to resort to the Aggregate Demand
Aggregate Supply model. You might not even need Aggregate Demand Aggregate
Supply to understand why we had inflation in 1966 and 1967 and really the late '60s generally. All you would have to do is think about entering into, or the beginning of LBJ's administration, the economy was already at high utilization. Unemployment was only at around 4% or 5%; 95%-96% of the labor force was employed. Factories were operating
at high utilization. Now we escalate the war. We're taking people who could have been employed in the domestic economy and they're going and fighting in battle. We need bullets, we need boats, we need fuel, we need all of these things. We need to utilize more
of domestic capacity to produce all of these things, so you can imagine that this dynamic was occurring; that you had to get firms
and people to tap out all of their extra
capacity, and then to do so they're essentially going to demand higher wages and higher prices. We wouldn't have necessarily
even had to resort to this to predict this higher inflation. Another way to think about
it is this is another way to justify an upward sloping aggregate supply curve in the short run, which is another way that we
described the same dynamic. They're all heavily, heavily related.